Tuesday, September 24, 2013

Firm-specific

Finally, firm-specific features also play an important role in shaping the
organization of international production; I focus here on two: size and strategic
focus.







One of the peculiar features of Japan’s international production networks in
electronics is the substantial role played by small and medium-sized enterprises
(SMEs).21 SMEs have higher OPRs than their large, vertically integrated
counterparts. This is true for smaller firms that produce final products but have a
quite narrow product focus, such as Aiwa (whose OPR exceeds 85 percent) or
Uniden (with an OPR close to 100 percent), but it is also true for the hundreds of relatively small subcontractors and component suppliers that have moved
production offshore to Southeast Asia and China.

This finding is somewhat surprising. Small firms have limited resources and
capabilities, many of them lack strong proprietary assets, and international
production involves transaction costs that most SMEs may simply be too small to
shoulder. Small firms can bypass such size-related barriers to internationalization if
they are part of a network centered around a core firm that reduces the
transaction costs involved in international production, such as the hierarchical
supplier networks that traditionally have characterized the Japanese electronics
industry. Small firms can also compensate for their size-related disadvantages by
limiting the geographic scope of their foreign investments. While large firms have
dispersed their production activities around the world, medium-sized firms cluster
their overseas operations in Taiwan, Korea, and Singapore; small firms are
concentrated mainly in Taiwan, but recently have expanded into China. Despite
a rapid growth of international production, smaller Japanese electronics firms rely
on a very limited international division of labor.

Even if product and size are held constant, however, it is important to
underline that substantial differences may remain across firms. This can be seen by
looking at consumer electronics and comparing Sanyo, the pioneer in establishing
Asian production networks, with the Matsushita group and Sony.

Sanyo’s founder was the brother-in-law of Konosuke Matsushita, who took
over most of the operations of the Matsushita group when it was broken up
under the US Occupation Authority. In Japan, Sanyo always remained a secondtier
competitor, and compensated with an aggressive early shift into international
production. In the early 1970s, Sanyo developed the so-called “one-third”
strategy for manufacturing capacity—one-third domestic manufacture for the
domestic market; one-third domestic manufacture for foreign markets (especially
higher-end segments); and one-third foreign manufacture for foreign markets. Sanyo aggressively focused its international production and sourcing on East Asia
in the second half of the 1970s, much earlier than any of its Japanese rivals.

Matsushita Electric Industrial Co. Ltd (MEI) is the world’s largest manufacturer
of consumer electronics and household appliances. Since the mid-1980s, it has
diversified aggressively into communications and factory automation equipment,
semiconductors, and video software, with the result that today the share of
industrial electronics and electronics components in its overall sales is roughly
equal to the share of consumer and household goods. For quite some time, this
giant conglomerate has been run like a loose network of (almost) independent
business units, with headquarters playing the neutral role of an arbiter. As long as
markets kept growing, this loose network organization was widely considered to
be a great strength, as it enabled the company to remain reasonably flexible
despite its huge size (Imai 1988). However, as demand growth slowed the hidden
costs of excessive decentralization and decision autonomy, such as duplication,
foregone economies of scale and self-generated price pressures became apparent.

Matsushita’s core competencies traditionally have been size-related advantages
in distribution and high-end manufacturing (in specialized affiliates like
Matsushita Kotobuki). It had tight control over the domestic distribution
channels for consumer electronics, and thus its expansion activities in East Asia
were geared more to the heavily protected domestic markets than to the
establishment of low-cost export platform production. Once Matsushita decided
to move to export platform production, however, it was able to do so on a
massive scale, rapidly neutralizing whatever first-mover advantages Sanyo may
have developed.

Sony, together with Sanyo, has one of the highest OPRs among large
diversified Japanese electronics firms; yet, its overseas production has remained
focused almost exclusively on the United States and Europe. Only since the late
1980s has the company begun to invest seriously in the development of an Asian
production network. Sony’s approach to international production reflects some
peculiar features of this company that have shaped its strategy. In 1952, when
Sony purchased a license for Western Electric’s transistor patent and began to
produce transistor radios under the model name Sony, the company decided to
focus on the high-income and high-growth markets in the United States and
Europe. Right from the beginning, the firm sought to develop its own brand name
image. Akio Morita, the company’s charismatic co-founder, spent considerable
time and energy on developing direct links with large US retailers to ensure that
Sony’s products would receive sufficient floor space.

Owing to the tremendous success of this strategy, Sony was under much less
pressure to internationalize than its rivals, who lacked similar image recognition
and concentrated on Asian markets. Sony was also reluctant to shift to export
platform production in East Asia and invested heavily in the automation of its
European and North American plants, including those in Mexico. Today Sony’s
Asian production networks are still relatively underdeveloped, but they are also
much less burdened than Sanyo and Matsushita with “deadwood,” surplus

capacities and duplication.

0 comments:

Post a Comment