Tuesday, September 24, 2013

The dominance of SMEs: a source of flexibility



SMEs have been the main carriers of Taiwan’s rapid development and remain
important today. In 1993, SMEs accounted for 96 percent of the total number of
companies, 69 percent of total employment, and 55 percent of Taiwan’s
manufactured exports (Chen et al. 1995). Taiwan today is home to more than 4,
000 electronics firms that produce a broad mix of PC-related products and
electronic components. With a few exceptions, such as the Tatung group, almost
all of these companies started out as small enterprises.
The role of SMEs as engines of growth and industrial transformation sets

Taiwan apart from South Korea, where huge and highly diversified
conglomerates (chaebol) have been the main carriers of the development of the
electronics industry.10 Almost without exception, the chaebol have targeted those
segments of the electronics industry that require huge investment outlays and
sophisticated mass production techniques for fairly homogeneous products such as
microwave ovens (MWOs), TV sets, VCRs, computer monitors, picture tubes,
and computer memory, especially dynamic random access memory (DRAM).
The result has been a heavy focus on assembly-type mass production activities
related to lower end consumer products and standard electronic components, and
weakness in more design-intensive sectors of the computer industry.

Why have Taiwanese firms succeeded in the computer industry while their
much larger and resource-rich Korean counterparts have largely failed? The answer lies in the fundamental characteristics of an industry in which high
volatility and uncertainty put a premium on flexibility and the capacity to adjust
to abrupt and frequently unexpected changes in demand and technology. Small
firm size is even an advantage.11 By combining incremental product innovation
with incredibly fast speed-to-market, Taiwanese firms have been able to establish
a strong international market position relatively early in the product cycle.

The primary source of this flexibility appears to be the specific organization of
the domestic supply base in Taiwan, especially for parts and components. Two
main features of this domestic supply base have contributed to the flexibility of
Taiwanese producers, the first being an extreme form of specialization. By
engaging in single tasks and by producing, purchasing, and selling in small lots,
subcontractors avoid heavy fixed capital costs. This, in turn, makes it relatively
easy to shift production at relatively short notice, and with a minimum of costs. The
second feature is a certain network structure of multiple, volatile and short-term
links that involve only limited financial and technology transfers. Spot-market
transactions play an important role, but so do “temporary spider web”
arrangements that are assembled for the duration of a particular job.12

The result of these characteristics is an extreme form of open and volatile
production networks, arguably even more so than the highly flexible production
networks that characterize California’s Silicon Valley.13 Firms maximize the
number of jobs in order to compensate for the razor-thin profit margins; as a
result, they avoid being locked into a particular production network. Domestic
supplier networks thus have been highly flexible and capable of rapid change but
are short-lived and foot-loose.

If flexibility constitutes one prerequisite for Taiwan’s competitive success in
computers, economies of scale and scope and speed-to-market have been of equal
importance.14 Entry barriers have increased for those stages of the value-chain
that are of critical importance for competitive success, including particularly
component manufacturing, where production-related scale economies remain
important. But the epicenter of competition has shifted beyond manufacturing to
R&D and other forms of intangible investment required to complement price
competition with product differentiation and speed-to-market. Only those
companies that are able to get the right product to the highest volume segment of
the market at the right time can survive. Being late is a disaster, and often forces
companies out of business.

In sum, what really matters for competitive success are substantial investments
in the formation of a firm’s technological and organizational capabilities. How
were Taiwanese computer companies able to successfully compete in an industry
where size-related advantages are of critical importance? And, more specifically,
what kind of organizational innovations have enabled Taiwanese firms to
overcome their size-related disadvantages?

In order to answer these questions, we need to examine issues of specialization
and coordination. Andersen (1996) has recently provided an interesting theoretical
explanation why excessive specialization may involve substantial trade-offs.15 He shows that as an economy becomes more specialized it increases the pressure for
standardization. This, in turn, may constrain innovation.16 The solution to this
dilemma is the establishment of tight linkages between firms along the supply
chain that enhance the prospects for inter-firm learning, for instance between end
product manufacturers and component suppliers.17

To understand how Taiwan avoided the dangers of excessive specialization and
established tight inter-firm linkages, it is important to correct some popular
misconceptions of the Taiwanese model. This is not an economy characterized by
atomistic competition. SMEs do play an important role, yet they survive as a
result of a combination of four forces: government policies that facilitated market
entry and upgrading; strong linkages with large Taiwanese firms and business
groups; the presence of foreign sales and manufacturing affiliates; and early

participation in international production networks.

0 comments:

Post a Comment