The governance
structures that determine whether control over international
production networks
is centralized or decentralized are highly sensitive to peculiar
features of national
institutions and markets. There is a broad
consensus that
Japanese companies, once they moved abroad, were less obsessed
with equity control
than American companies.This is a reflection of important differences in the
domestic capital markets of both countries and the fact that Japanese firms
have had, until quite recently, ample access to patient capital. Some observers
also claim that Japanese firms, especially in East Asia, are more willing to
engage in joint ventures and other forms
of inter-firm cooperation than American companies because of domestic relations
with suppliers. “[A]ccustomed to operating in their home market through an
extensive network of cooperation agreements, [Japanese firms] show a higher
propensity to enter partnerships in Asia than American
As long as their
objective was the penetration of protected domestic markets,
Japanese
subsidiaries in Asia had relatively strong local roots; local content was
substantial, and
this gave rise to a first generation of domestic support industries.
At the same time,
these subsidiaries often had considerable leeway with respect to
the main objective:
how to reap the windfall profits available in highly protected
domestic markets.
The Matsushita group
provides an example. Its core company Matsushita
Electric Industrial
(MEI) arguably is “…the company most deeply involved in
East Asian electronics,
and most representative of the Japanese approach.”
. Matsushita’s
involvement in East Asia started in the early 1960s with minority joint
ventures strictly targeted at heavily protected domestic markets. The so-called
“mini-Matsus” originally produced simple products like batteries, radios,
electric fans, rice cookers and other low-end home appliances, small TV sets
and some related components. As minority joint ventures, most of these local
affiliates had considerable decision autonomy not only for employment, work
practices, and salary, but also on how to organize production, support services
(quality control and maintenance) and procurement. Decision autonomy was
probably most pronounced in the choice of marketing approaches and distribution
channels. Considerable local linkages developed from these investments, and
local value-added increased sharply, often, however, at the expense of cost
efficiency and quality.
Once their objective
shifted from the penetration of domestic markets to
exports, Matsushita
increasingly relied on 100 percent affiliates or at least majority
joint ventures.
Local linkages declined as components were procured either
directly from Japan
or from Matsushita’s affiliates within the region. This general
pattern has been
followed by all Japanese electronics firms: as they shift to export
platform production,
they close their Asian production networks to outsiders by
centralizing almost
all strategic decision-making and high value-added activities in
Japan. Until a few
years ago, sourcing components from independent local
suppliers played a
very marginal role, and was restricted to technically simple lowend
components and
support activities; almost all high value-added components
were imported from
Japan.3 This heavy dependence on Japan appears to have
reached its peak by
1992.4 Between fiscal year (FY) 1991 and FY 1992, East Asian
affiliates of
Japanese electronics firms increased their procurement from Japan from
less than 40 percent
to nearly 47 percent, much higher than the average share of
38 percent reported
for all industries. While the share of intra-regional
procurement has
stagnated at around 15 percent, there has been a substantial
decline in local
purchases from nearly 44 percent to less than 37 percent.
The closed and
Japan-centered nature of the Asian production networks of
Japanese electronics
firms extends well beyond the sphere of procurement.
Japanese electronics
firms rely much less on local managers and engineers in their
Asian affiliates than
their American and European counterparts do, leaving Asian
affiliates little
scope for autonomous decisions. Japanese electronics firms routinely
engage in sound and
systematic “on-the-job” training. Most of the training
however remains
restricted to simple operational capabilities required for
production and
maintenance.6
We also find only a
limited transfer of the Japanese production model to Asian
affiliates of
Japanese electronics firms. In most affiliates, seniority-based wage
systems, job
rotation, “life-long” employment, quality control circles, and just-intime
(JIT) management
approaches play an insignificant role. Often a crude
Fordism prevails, at
least during the initial phase of production.7 This contrasts
with the situation
in the United States and Europe, where Japanese firms have
made serious
attempts to transfer key elements of their domestic production
system and to adapt
them to the peculiarities of local institutions and labor
markets. In contrast
to the situation in Asia, Japanese IPNs in the United States
and Europe have
undergone a certain limited convergence with the investment
patterns of American
and European firms (Abo 1993; Encarnation and Mason
1994; and Gittelman
and Graham 1994).
The issue of
governance structure thus leaves us with a few puzzles. In contrast
to a general
perception that Japanese firms are more willing to engage in
partnerships in East
Asia, we find that this has not been the case in the electronics
industry. Early
partnerships serving local markets gave way to highly centralized
and closed
governance structures as production moved toward exports for third
markets.
0 comments:
Post a Comment